C § E § A § L |
Center for the Economic Analysis of Law |
WASHINGTON, DC |
|
|
|
Nicaragua: How Problems in the Framework for Secured Transactions
Limit Access to Credit |
|
Heywood W. Fleisig Nuria de la Peña February 1998 |
|
© Copyright 1997, Center for the Economic Analysis of Law. All Rights Reserved.
* The views and interpretations expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views and policies of the Center for the Economic Analysis of Law (CEAL).
Heywood W. Fleisig is Director of Research at CEAL, Nuria
de la Peña is Research Associate and Director of Operations in Latin America at
CEAL. The authors thank Violeta
Rosenthal, Rodrigo Chaves, Ronald C.C. Cuming, Alejandro Garro, Lance Girton,
Roberto Muguillo, Alfonso Ortega, Graciela Rodriguez-Ferrand, and John A.
Spanogle for extensive and helpful advice and comment. Many Nicaraguans have generously given their
time to explain their perspectives on these problems. The authors thank them for their help. Any errors, however, entirely remain the responsibility of the
authors.
In Nicaragua, several problems in the framework for secured transactions limit access to credit in agriculture. These problems involve creating, perfecting, and enforcing security interests in movable property –- such as inventory, equipment, cattle, and accounts receivables. Creating a security interest in movable collateral --typically the pledge-- is costly. At the same time, many types of property are not envisioned as possible objects of collateral under the pledge laws. Perfection rules do not call for registries that provide for a public and inexpensive means of finding out whether prior encumbrances in collateral exist. The rules for the priority of secured lenders do not clearly rank interests in collateral. Finally, the rules for enforcing security interests establish a costly process (with substantial court procedures) -- a process so lengthy that most movable collateral depreciates in value before it can be repossessed and sold to pay a defaulted loan.
These problems in Nicaragua’s framework for secured transactions limit access to credit in agriculture. First, because farmers and agricultural intermediaries in the rural chain of credit have no means to safely secure loans with the physical capital that they actually have – capital in movable property. Second, because sellers of this capital cannot safely sell on credit using as collateral the movable property being sold. Third, because this defective framework for secured transactions makes it difficult for formal sector lenders to provide refinancing for the natural conduits of rural credit, especially to buyers of farm products and to dealers and suppliers of farm inputs. This limited access to credit is a key constraint on rural development.
Nicaragua:
Access to Credit and the Framework for Secured Transactions
Improving access to
credit in agriculture is often seen as a key element in rural development
strategy -- because projects exist that could increase the incomes of farmers
and other rural businesses if they only had access to that credit. Nicaraguans
interviewed in the course of this study offered many examples of such
investments. Equipment dealers, for example, believed that increases in sales
of 200% to 300% were possible at current interest rates if they were able to
sell with four year loans instead of one or two year loans. A broad range of
producers -- coffee, fruit, cotton, vegetables, and timber -- believed that loans for seed, fertilizer,
pesticides, and fungicides could easily double output.
Similarly, access to
credit is often seen as an important tool in attacking rural poverty.
Profitable projects do exist that could raise income. Also increasing access to
credit would achieve other social objectives, such as improving the
independence and self-reliance of the target groups, increasing agricultural
self-sufficiency, or permitting the able rural poor to swiftly raise their
earning prospects. Again this was broadly confirmed in the interviews conducted
in the course of this research. However, the smallest producers had limited
access to credit, and then only if tied into an established monopoly exporting
chain. That market power gave lenders security in their loans. Otherwise, small
borrowers had no access to credit at all. At the same time, access to credit in
Nicaragua was limited even for the largest and most prosperous companies. By
contrast, similar companies in the United States and Canada would have ample
access to credit at interest rates close to the government borrowing-rate. In
this way, the problem in the framework for secured transactions imposes a large
competitive disadvantage on Nicaragua agro-processors that will grow worse as
economic integration improves with North America.
There has long been
concern in Nicaragua that banks and other private formal sector institutions do
not deliver sufficient credit to farmers and other rural businesses. Of
particular concern has been the absence of credit to small farmers.
Consequently, the government, and bilateral and multilateral donors have
focused on different institutional innovation that could improve the delivery
of such credit.
At first, the
government attempted to disburse these credit lines through state banks, and
state guarantee funds. These attempts
were a costly failure. Private lenders
would not make these loans because they are too risky to set up and collect against
movable collateral since the legal and institutional framework for loans secured
with movable property collateral does not provide for the key features of a
safe system. When public lenders made them, they too found them indeed
uncollectible. Moreover, public lenders
faced political pressures to charge uneconomically low interest rates, to lend
to politically favored groups who were not always able to pay, and were less
enthusiastic in debt recovery than would have been private sector
institutions. Poor performance combined
with visible failure to reach target groups.
This led to plans to refinance agricultural loans and dissolve public
lending institutions and guarantee funds.
In its place, the
government and donors set up a system that would disburse through private
for-profit institutions. This improved
the efficiency of these onlending operations. Private lenders, in the framework
of a substantially strengthened system of supervision and regulation, took
great care to disburse only where loans could be collected. However, in most
cases this improvement in efficiency took place at the expense of reaching the
target groups -- the price of improved efficiency was that target groups had
even less access to credit.
In Nicaragua, problems
in the legal framework for secured transactions continue to block access to
credit. They restrict formal sector
institutions in their direct delivery of credit to farmers and small and medium
size agricultural enterprises. They
limit formal sector financial institutions in their refinancing of credit extended
by rural equipment dealers and suppliers.
They hamper innovative new institutions that aim at delivering such
credit:
In the secondary
market for agricultural credit, two important problems surfaced. First,
problems in the framework for secured transactions made the loan portfolios of
rural lenders that are secured with movable collateral are often “non-legal” or
“risky” to collect. Bundled together, they still represented risky collateral
for a larger loan with larger lenders or for backing up securities. Second, Nicaragua’s framework for secured
transactions does not provide for security interests in portfolios of unsecured
and secured loans (accounts receivables and chattel paper financing). Thus, it
is costly and risky (if not, “non-legal”), to use portfolios of secured or
unsecured loans as collateral for a loan with banks or finance companies.
This paper reflects
interviews of producers of coffee, fruits, peanuts, shrimp; manufacturers;
distributors of construction, and farm machinery; traders in farm products;
sellers of fertilizers and pesticides; the regulatory team of the
Superintendency of Banks; bank lawyers; registry officials; and managers medium
and large banking institutions, financial companies, warehouse operators, and
retail businesses.
Most businesses
interviewed operated simultaneously as lenders, credit-sellers, borrowers, and
credit-buyers in the Nicaraguan credit chain. In each case, however, access to
credit was typically limited to the value of real estate they could offer as
collateral, using a mortgage and borrowing from only one lender. For a few commodities, additional credit was
available through warrants on merchandise immobilized in warehouses; for a few
lenders, the pledge on equipment was useful.
However, the current
provision of credit does not adequately serve the needs of Nicaraguan
producers. For example, in the practice
of the trade in coffee production, a rural coffee purchaser will buy from the
final producer, who typically is a smallholder operating on a small plot. The purchaser will establish a working
relationship over years with their producers and extend credit for fertilizer,
fungicide, and pesticides. The amount
of credit they offer will depend on their confidence in the ability of the
final borrower to repay. There is no
security. This unsecured lending system
depends on the purchaser’s personal knowledge of the small producer. Such a system underlies trillions of dollars
of loans in North America. However,
unlike North American lenders, the purchaser has a limited ability to offer unsecured
credit: the amount that the coffee purchaser can lend is limited by his own
access to capital. Where the North American lender could use the portfolio of
these well-performing loans to secure loans from a larger formal sector lender,
such as a bank, the Nicaraguan purchaser cannot. Rather, the coffee purchaser’s
access to capital is limited because of the collateral restrictions placed by
the legal and institutional framework for secured transactions. The purchaser
could, of course, get a mortgage on real estate. However, the business of the purchaser does not involve many
assets tied up in real estate. Rather, the purchaser has movable property as
assets: tangible movable property -- trucks, rotating inventories of coffee, or
fruit -- and intangible movable property -- accounts receivable from the small
producers, accounts receivable from the coffee exporters in the cities. In Nicaragua, all of this movable property
must be financed from the purchaser’s own capital; none of this movable
property serves as collateral for a loan that would permit the purchaser to
expand his operation by offering more credit to his producers.
Some borrowers give
the appearance of using their machinery, inventories, and receivables as
collateral. Typically, though, that financing was illusory. Rather, banks would give firms a credit line
based on the firms' real estate holdings -- bienes
inmuebles. Subsequent financing secured by movable
property would usually be deducted from this credit line. No additional credit
was granted to companies that increased their accounts receivable with more
sales or that had double their movable property inventory through a more
efficient production of agricultural produces.
Their available credit reached a ceiling determined by their ownership
of real estate, and no credit was granted secured solely on their assets in
movable property. Few types of property, besides real estate, seemed to
"really" serve as collateral in the sense that additional offerings
of such collateral persuaded lenders to offer additional credit. Such a limitation represents a near-fatal
constraint. It means that as rural
demand for credit for movable property rises – such as equipment, inventories,
pesticides, herbicides, or seed – that credit cannot rise to accommodate it. In
each case, legal and institutional limits in using movable property as
collateral for loans limited access to credit to profitable transactions and
growing businesses in agriculture.
These limits in using
movable property as collateral for loans do not arise from macroeconomic
problems or from high intermediation spread, but from problems in the
Nicaraguan secured transactions framework that makes movable property a very
risky collateral.
These problems in the Nicaraguan secured transactions framework have
been observed in other countries such as Argentina, Mexico, Uruguay, Bolivia,
Honduras, and El Salvador, that share Nicaragua's Civil Code tradition. But it is not confined to these countries. Bangladesh, India, and Pakistan are Common
Law countries with similar problems that arise from an inadequate framework for
security interests in movable property.
Next steps
The next steps warranted by the findings in this report include:
· Prepare a draft law addressing the problems set out here.
·
Prepare a report assessing the options for reform of
the registration system of security interests in movable property, being
especially careful to delineate private and public responsibilities
·
Prepare project for the reform of the such registration
system